Alternative Pathways of Social Evolution


Alternative Pathways of Social Evolution Alternative Pathways of Social Evolution
Download
Authors: Bondarenko, Dmitri M.; Grinin, Leonid; Korotayev, Andrey
Journal: Social Evolution & History. Volume 1, Number 1 / March 2002

It has always been peculiar to evolutionists to compare social and biological evolution, the latter as visualized by Charles Dar­win.1 But it also seems possible and correct to draw an analogy with another great discovery in the field of evolutionary biology, with the homologous series of Nikolay Vavilov (1921; 1927; 1967). However, there is no complete identity between cultural parallelism and biological homologous series. Vavilov studied the morphological homology, whereas our focus within the realm of social evolution is the functional one. No doubt, the morphological homomorphism also happens in the process of social evolution (e.g. in the Hawaii Islands where a type of the sociocultural or­ganization surprisingly similar with the ones of other highly devel­oped parts of Polynesia had independently formed by the end" of the 18th century [Sahlins 1972/1958; Goldman 1970; Earle 1978]). But this topic is beyond the present paper’ sproblematique.

What is important for us here is that there are reasons to sup­pose that an equal level of sociopolitical (and cultural) complexity (which makes it possible to solve equally difficult problems faced by societies) can be achieved not only in various forms but on es­sentially different evolutionary pathways, too. Thus, it is possible to achieve the same level of system complexity through differing pathways of evolution which appeared simultaneously (and even prior to the formation of Homo Sapiens Sapiens [Butovskaya and Feinberg 1993; Butovskaya 1994; 2000; Butovskaya, Korotayev, and Kazankov 2000]) and increased in quantity alongside so­ciocultural advancement (Pavlenko 1996: 229–251; 2000). Diver­sity could be regarded as one of the most important preconditions of the evolutionary process. This implies that the transition to any qualitatively new forms is normally not possible without a suffi­cient level of variability of sociocultural forms (among both the given culture’ s predecessors and contemporaries).

Within the first level of analysis, all evolutionary variability can be reduced to two principally different groups of homologous series (Bondarenko 1997: 12–15; 1998a; 2000; Bondarenko and Korotayev 1999; 2000b; Korotayev et al. 2000). Earlier these al­ternatives were distinguished either as ‘hierarchical’ vs. ‘nonhier-archical’ (e.g. Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a), or ‘hierarchical’ vs. ‘heterarchical’ (e.g. Fiirenrdcri, Qurnley, and Levy 1995; Crumley 2001).

In a recent publication on the problem of heterarchy the latter is defined as ‘... the relation of elements to one another when they are unranked or when they possess the potential for being ranked in a number of different ways’ (Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 3; see also Crumley 1979: 144). It is clear that the second version of heterarchy is most relevant for the study of the complex societies.

However, when we have a system of elements which ‘possess the potential for being ranked in a number of different ways’, it seems impossible to speak about the absence of hierarchy. In this case we rather deal with a system of heterarchically arranged hier­archies. Hence, it does not appear reasonable to denote the heter­archy alternative as ‘hierarchy’. We would rather suggest to desig­nate it as ‘homoarchy’ which could be defined as ‘...the relation of elements to one another when they possess the potential for be­ing ranked in one way only’. Totalitarian regimes of any time give us plenty of examples of such a sociocultural situation when the ruled have no chances to get ranked above the rulers in any possi­ble contexts. This stands in a sharp contrast with, say, an arche­typal example of a complex heterarchical system – the civil com­munity (polis) of Athens (the 5Ш–4Ш centuries ВС) where the citizens ranked lower within one hierarchy (e.g. the military one) could well be ranked higher in many other possible respects (e.g. economically, or within the subsystem of civil/religious magis­trates). Consequently, it was impossible to say that one citizen was higher than any other in any absolute sense.

On the other hand, it seems necessary to stress that it appears impossible to find not only any human cultures totally lacking any hierarchies (including informal ones), but also any totally homoar-chical cultures. Hence, though in order to simplify our analysis in this paper we speak about heterarchical and homoarchical evolu­tionary pathways, in fact we are dealing here with heterarchy-homoarchy axis along which one could range all the known human cultures. Within this range there does not seem to be any distinct border between homoarchical and heterarchical cultures; hence, in reality it might be more appropriate to speak not about just two evolutionary pathways (heterarchical and homoarchical), but about a potentially infinite number of such pathways, and, thus, finally not about evolutionary pathways, but rather about evolutionary probability field (see for detail Korotayev et al. 2000). Yet, as was mentioned above, in order to simplify our analysis we speak about just two alternative pathways.

In particular, until recently it was considered self-evident that just the formation of the state2 marked the end of the ‘Primitive Epoch’ and alternatives to the state did not actually exist. All the stateless societies were considered pre-state ones, standing on the single evolutionary staircase squarely below the states. Nowadays postulates about the state as the only possible form of political and sociocultural organization of the post-primitive society, about a-priori higher level of development of a state society in comparison with any non-state one do not seem so undeniable as a few years ago. It has become evident that the non-state societies are not nec­essarily less complex and less efficient. The problem of existence of non-state but not primitive (i.e. principally поп- and not pre-state) societies, alternatives to the state (as the allegedly inevitable post-primitive form of the sociopolitical organization) deserves attention.

Of course, in no way do we reject the fact of existence and im­portance of the states in world history. What we argue, is that the state is not the only possible post-’ primitive’ evolutionary form. From our point of view, the state is nothing more than one of many forms of the post-primitive sociopolitical organization; these forms are alternative to each other and are able to transform to one another without any loss in the general level of complexity. Hence, the degree of sociopolitical centralization and ‘homoarchization’ is not a perfect criterion for evaluating a society’s evolutionary level, though it is regarded as such within unilinear concepts of social evolution.

As Brumfiel wrote several years ago, ‘the coupling of [socio­political] differentiation and hierarchy is so firm in our minds that it takes tremendous intellectual efforts even imagine what differ­entiation without hierarchy could be’ (Brumfiel 1995: 130).3 Usu­ally, even if the very existence of complex but non-homoarchical cultures is recognized, they are regarded as a historical fortuity, as an anomaly. Such cultures are declared as if capable to reach rather low levels of complexity only, as if incapable to find inter­nal stability (Tuden and Marshall 1972: 454–456).

Thus, on the further level of analysis the dichotomy turns out not to be rigid at all as far as actual organization of any society employs both vertical (dominance – subordination) and horizontal (apprehended as ties among equals) links. Furthermore, in the course of their history, societies (including archaic cultures) turn out capable to change models of sociopolitical organization radi­cally, transforming from homoarchical into heterarchical or vice versa (Crumley 1987: 164–165; 1995: 4; 2001; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000c; Dozhdev 2000; Kradin 2000a). Perhaps the most well known historical example of the latter case is Rome where the Republic was established and further democratized with the Plebian political victories. Note that in the course of such transformations the organizational background changes, but the overall level of cultural complexity may not only increase or de­crease but may well stay practically the same (for examples from ancient and medieval history of Europe, the Americas, Asia see, e.g. van der Vliet 1987: Ferguson 1991; Korotayev 1995a; 1996a; Levy 1995; Lynsha 1998; Beliaev 2000; Chamblee 2000: 15–35; Dozhdev 2000; Kowalewski 2000; Kradin 2000a).

Nevertheless, vertical and horizontal links play different parts in different societies at every concrete moment. Already among the primates with the same level of morphological and cognitive development, and even among primate populations belonging to the same species, one could observe both more and less hierarchi­cally organized groups. Hence, the non-linearity of sociopolitical evolution appears to originate already before the Homo Sapiens Sapiens formation (Butovskaya and Feinberg 1993; Butovskaya 1994; Butovskaya, Korotayev, and Kazankov 2000).

Let us consider now in more detail one of the most influential and widespread unilineal evolutionary schemes, the one proposed by Service (1962/1971; its outline is, however, already contained in Sahlins 1960: 37): band – tribe – chiefdom – state. The scheme implies that the growth of the political complexity (at least up to the stage of the agrarian state) is inevitably accompanied by the growth of the inequality, stratification, the social distance between the rulers and the ruled, the ‘authoritarianism’ and hierarchization of the political system, decrease of the political participation of the main mass of population etc. Of course, these two sets of parame­ters seem to be related rather closely. It is evident that we observe here a certain correlation, and a rather strong one. But, no doubt, this is just a correlation, and by no means a functional dependence. Of course, this correlation implies a perfectly possible line of so­ciopolitical evolution – from an egalitarian, acephalous band, through a big-man village community with much more pro­nounced inequality and political hierarchy, to an ‘authoritarian’ village community with a strong power of its chief (found e.g. among some Indians of the North-West Coast – see e.g. Cameiro 2000), and than through the true chiefdoms having even more pro­nounced stratification and concentration of the political power in the hands of the chief, to the complex chiefdoms where the politi­cal inequality parameters reach a qualitatively higher levels, and finally to the agrarian state where all such parameters reach their culmination (though one could move even further, up to the level of the ‘empire’ [e.g. Adams 1975]). However, it is very important to stress that on each level of the growing political complexity one could find easily evident alternatives to this evolutionary line.

Let us start with the human societies of the simplest level of sociocultural complexity. Indeed, one can easily observe that acephalous egalitarian bands are found among most of the unspe-cialized hunter-gatherers. However, as has been shown by Wood-burn (1972; 1979; 1980; 1982; 1988a; 1988b) and Artemova (1987; 1991; 1993; 2000a; 2000b; Chudinova 1981; see also Whyte 1978: 49–94), some of such hunter-gatherers (the inegalitarian ones, first of all most of the Australian aborigines) display a significantly different type of sociopolitical organization with much more structured political leadership concentrated in the hands of relatively hierarchically organized elders, with a pro­nounced degree of inequality both between the men and women, and among the men themselves.

On the next level of the political complexity we can also find communities with both homoarchical and heterarchical political organization. One can mention e.g. the well-known contrast be­tween the Indians of the Califomian North-West and South-East:

The Califomian chiefs were in the center of economic life, they exercised their control over the production, distribution and exchange of the social product, and their power and authority were based mainly on this. Gradually the power of the chiefs and elders acquired the hereditary character, it became a typical phenomenon for California... Only the tribes populating the North-West of Cali­fornia, notwithstanding their respectively developed and complex material culture, lacked the explicitly expressed social roles of the chiefs characteristic for the rest of California. At the meantime they new slavery... The population of this region had an idea of personal wealth... (Kabo 1986: 20).

One can also immediately recall the communities of Ifugao (e.g. Barton 1922; Meshkov 1982: 183–197) lacking any pro­nounced authoritarian political leadership compared with the one of the communities of the North-West Coast, but with a compara­ble level of overall sociopolitical and sociocultural complexity.

Hence, already on the levels of simple and middle range com­munities we observe several types of alternative sociopolitical forms, each of which should be denoted with a separate term. The possible alternatives to the chiefdom in the prehistoric Southwest Asia, heterarchical systems of complex acephalous communities with a pronounced autonomy of single family households have been analyzed recently by Berezkin who suggests reasonably Ара Tanis as their ethnographic parallel (1995a; 1995b; 2000). Frantsouzoff finds an even more developed example of such type of polities in ancient South Arabia in Wadi Hadramawt of the 1st millennium ВС (1995; 1997; 2000).

Another evident alternative to the chiefdom is constituted by the tribal organization. As is well known, the tribe has found itself on the brink of being evicted from the evolutionary models (Townsend 1985: 146; Carneiro 1987: 760). However, the political forms entirely identical with what was described by Service as the tribe could be actually found in e.g. medieval and modern Middle East (up to the present): these tribal systems normally comprise several communities and often have precisely the type of political leadership described by Service as typical for the tribe (Service 1971/1962: 103–104; Dresch 1984: 39, 41).

The point is that we are dealing here with some type of polity that could not be identified either with bands, or with village communities (because such tribes normally comprise more than one community), or with chiefdoms (because they have an entirely different type of political leadership), or, naturally, with states. They could not be inserted easily either in the scheme somewhere between the village and the chiefdom. Indeed, as has been shown convincingly by Carneiro (see e.g. 1970; 1981; 1987; 1991; 2000), chiefdoms normally arose as a result of political centralization of a few communities without the stage of the tribe preceding this. On the other hand, a considerable amount of evidence could be pro­duced suggesting that in the Middle East many tribes arose as a result of political decentralization of chiefdoms which preceded the tribes in time. It is also important to stress that this could not in any way be identified with a ‘regression’, ‘decline’, or ‘degenera­tion’, as we can observe in many of such cases that political de­centralization is accompanied by the increase (rather than de­crease) of overall sociocultural complexity (Korotayev 1995a; 1995c; 1995d; 1996a; 1996b; 1996c; 1997; 1998; 2000a; 2000b). Hence, in many respects tribal systems of the Middle Eastern type appear to be chiefdom alternatives (rather than chiefdom predeces­sors).

We have argued elsewhere (Korotayev 1995b) that in general there is an evident evolutionary alternative to the development of the rigid supra-communal political structures (chiefdom – complex chiefdom – state) constituted by the development of internal communal structures together with soft supra-communal systems not alienating communal sovereignty (various confederations, am-phictyonies etc.). One of the most impressive results of the socio­political development along this evolutionary line is the Greek poleis (see [Berent 1994; 1996; 2000a; 2000b] regarding the statelessness of this type of political systems) some of which reached overall levels of complexity quite comparable not only with the ones of chiefdoms, but also with the one of states. The same can be said about its Roman analogue, the civitas (Shtaerman 1989). Note that polis/civitas as a form of sociopolitical organiza­tion was known far beyond the Classical world, both in geographi­cal and chronological sense (Korotayev 1995b; Bondarenko 1998b), though quite a number of scholars still insist on its uniqueness.

The ‘tribal’ and ‘polis’ series seem to constitute separate evo­lutionary lines, with some distinctive features: the ‘polis’ forms imply the power of the ‘magistrates’ elected in one or another way for fixed periods and controlled by the people in the absence (or near-absence) of any formal bureaucracy. Within the tribal sys­tems we observe the absence of any offices whose holders would be obeyed simply because they hold posts of a certain type, and the order is sustained by elaborate mechanisms of mediation and search for consensus.

There is also a considerable number of other complex stateless polities (like the ones of the Cossacks of Ukraine and Southern Russia till the end of the 17th century [Chirkin 1955; Rozner 1970; Nikitin 1987; etc.], the Celts of the 5tn-ist centuries ВС [Kradin 2000c: 149], or the Icelandic polity of the ‘Age of Democracy’ till the middle of the 13th century [Olgeirsson 1957; Gurevich 1972; Steblin-Kamenskij 1984]) which could not yet be denoted with any commonly accepted terms, and whose own self-designations are often too complex (like Kazach ‘e Vojsko) to have any chance to get transformed into general terms. Such examples can of course be further multiplied.

And this is not all. There is another evident problem with Sendee’s scheme. It is evidently pre- ‘Wallersteinian’, not touched by any world-system discussions, quite confident about the possi­bility of the use of a single polity as a unit of social evolution. It might be not so important if Service were speaking about the ty­pology of polities; yet, he speaks about the ‘levels of cultural inte­gration’, and within such a context the world-system dimension should be evidently taken into consideration4.

The point is that the same overall level of complexity could be achieved both through the development of a single polity and through the development of a politically uncentralized interpolity network. This alternative was already noticed by Wallerstein (1974; 1979; 1987) who viewed it as a dichotomy: world-economy world-empire. Note that according to Wallerstein these are considered precisely as alternatives, and not two stages of so­cial evolution. As one would expect, we agree with Wallerstein whole-heartedly at this point. However, we also find here a certain oversimplification. In general, we would like to stress that we are dealing here with a particular case of a much more general set of evolutionary alternatives.

The development of a politically uncentralized interpolity net­work became an effective alternative to the development of a sin­gle polity long before the rise of the first empires. As an example, we could mention the interpolity communication network of the Mesopotamian civil-temple communities of the first half of the 3millennium ВС which sustained a much higher level of techno­logical development than that of the politically unified Egyptian state, contemporary to it. Note that the intercommunal communi­cation networks already constitute an effective evolutionary alter­native to the chiefdom. E.g. the sociopolitical system of the Ара Tanis should be better described as an intercommunal network of a few communities (incidentally, in turn acting as a core for another wider network including the neighboring less developed polities [chiefdoms and sovereign communities] – see Fiihrer-Haimendorf 1962).

We also do not find it productive to describe this alternative type of cultural integration as a world-economy. The point is that such a designation tends to downplay the political and cultural di­mension of such systems. Take for example, the Classical Greek inter-polis system. The level of complexity of many Greek poleis was rather low even in comparison with a complex chiefdom. However, they were parts of a much larger and much .more com­plex entity constituted by numerous economic, political and cul­tural links and shared political and cultural norms. The economic links no doubt played some role within this system. But links of other types were not less important. Take, e.g. the norm according to which the inter-poleis wars stopped during the Olympic Games, which guaranteed the secure passage of people, and consequently the circulation of enormous quantities of energy, matter and in­formation within the territory far exceeding the one of an average complex chiefdom. The existence of the inter-poleis communica­tion network made it possible, say, for a person born in one polis to go to get his education in another polis and to establish his school in a third. The existence of this system reduced the de-structiveness of inter-poleis warfare for a long time. It was a basis on which it was possible to undertake important collective actions (which turned out to be essential at the age of the Greek-Persian wars). As a result, the polis with a level of complexity lower than the one of the complex chiefdom, turned out to be part of a system whose complexity was quite comparable with that of the state (and not only the early one).

The same can be said about the intersocietal communication network of Medieval Europe (comparing its complexity in this case with an average world-empire). Note that in both cases some parts of the respective systems could be treated as elements of wider world-economies. On the other hand, not all the parts of such communication networks were quite integrated economically. This shows that the world-economies were not the only possible type of politically decentralized intersocietal networks. Actually, in both cases we are dealing with the politically decentralized civilization, which for most of human history over the last few millennia, constituted the most effective alternative to the world-empire. Of course, many of such civilizations could be treated as parts of larger world-economies. Wallerstein suggests that in the age of complex societies only the world-economies and world-empires (‘historical systems’, i.e. the largest units of social evolu­tion) could be treated as units of social evolution in general. Yet we believe that both politically centralized and decentralized civi­lizations should also be treated as such. One should stress again the importance of the cultural dimension of such systems. Of course, the exchange of bulk goods was important. But exchange of information was also important. Note that the successful devel­opment of science both in Classical Greece and Medieval Europe became only possible through an intensive intersocietal informa­tion exchange, whereas the development of science in Europe af­fected, to a significant extent, the evolution of the Modern World-System.

It is important to stress that the intersocietal communication networks could appear among much less complex societies (Wal­lerstein has denoted them as ‘mini-systems’ without actually studying them, for a recent review of the research on the archaic intersocietal networks see Chase-Dunn and Grimes 1995; Chase-Dunn and Hall 1993; 1994; 1995; 1997). Already it seems possible to speak about a communication network covering most of abo­riginal Australia. Again we come here across a similar phenome­non-a considerable degree of cultural complexity (complex forms of rituals, mythology, arts, and dance well comparable with the ones of early agriculturists) observed among populations with an apparently rather simple political organization. This could largely be explained by the fact that relatively simple Australian local groups were parts of a much more complex whole: a huge intersocietal communication network that apparently covered most of Australia (e.g. Bakhta, Senyuta 1972; Artemova 1987).

Thus, it is possible to contrast societies that followed the path­way of political centralization and ‘authoritarianization’ with cul­tures that further elaborated and perfected democratic communal backgrounds and corresponding self-government institutions. However, such a culture as the Benin Kingdom of the 13tn–19tn centuries can make the picture of sociopolitical evolution even more versatile. In particular, it reveals that not only heterarchical but also homoarchical societies can reach a very high (incompara­bly higher than that of complex chiefdoms) level of sociocultural complexity and political centralization still never transforming into a state during the whole long period of existence. The Benin evidence also testifies that local community’ s autonomy is not a guarantee of complex society’ s advancement along the hierarchi­cal pathway. We have suggested elsewhere to define this form of sociopolitical organization as ‘megacommunity’ (see e.g. Bon-darenko 1994; 1995a: 276–284; 1995b; 2001: 232–249). Its struc­ture may be depicted in the shape of four concentric circles form­ing an upset cone. These ‘circles’ are as follows: the extended family, extended-family community (in which familial ties were supplemented by those of neighbor ones), chiefdom, and finally, the broadest circle that included all the three narrower ones, that is the megacommunity as such (the Benin Kingdom as a whole). The specific characteristic of megacommunity is its ability to organize a complex, ‘many-tier’ society predominantly on the basis of transformed kinship principle within rather vast territories.

Still, another evident alternative to the state seems to be repre­sented by the supercomplex chiefdoms created by some nomads of Eurasia – the number of the structural levels within such chiefdoms appear to be equal, or even to exceed those within the average state, but they have an entirely different type of political organization and political leadership; such type of political entities do not appear to have been ever created by the agriculturists (e.g. Kradin 1992: 146–152; 1996; 2000a; 2000b).

Besides the Benin megacommunity and nomadic supercomplex chiefdoms, the first half of the 19Ш century Zulu power can serve as an example at this point. Within that vast and mighty militaris­tic power one can observe high degree of supracommunal institu­tions’ hierarchization and high rigidity of this institutional hierarchy (see, e.g. Gluckman 1940; Ritter 1955). Societies with profoundly elaborated rigid caste systems may be a homoarchical alternative to also homoarchical (by the very definition; see Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 533–596, 637–650) early states, too (Quigley 1999: 114–169; Kobishchanov 2000: 64).

So, alternativity characterizes not only two basic macrogroups of human associations, i.e. homoarchical and heterarchical socie­ties. Alternativity does exist within each of them, too. In particular, within the upper range of complexity and integrativity of the sociopolitical organization the state (at least in the pre-industrial world) ‘competes’ with not only heterarchical systems of institu­tions (e.g. with polis) but also with some forms of sociopolitical organization not less homoarchical than the state.

Among numerous factors capable to influence the nature of this or that society, the family and community type characteristic of it seems to deserve notice. The distinction in the correlation of kin and neighborhood (territorial) lines is in its turn connected with the dominant type of community (as a universal substratum social institution). A cross-cultural research conducted earlier (Bondarenko and Korotayev 1999; 2000b) has generally corroborated the initial hypothesis (Bondarenko 1997: 13–14; 1998b: 198–199) that the extended-family community in which vertical social ties and non-democratic value system are usually vividly expressed, being given the shape of kinship relations (elder – younger), is more characteristic of homoarchical societies5. Heterarchical so­cieties appear to be more frequently associated with the territorial communities consisting of nuclear families in which social ties are horizontal and apprehended as neighborhood ties among those equal in rights6.

In the course of our cross-cultural research in the community forms, another factor important for determining societies’ homo-archization vs. heterarchization was revealed. It appeared that probability of a democratic (heterarchical) sociopolitical organi­zation development is higher in cultures where monogamous rather polygynous families dominate (Korotayev and Bondarenko 2000).

However, besides social factors (including those mentioned above), a set of phenomena stemming from the fact that political culture is a reflection of a society’ s general culture type, is also important for determining its evolutionary pathway. The general culture type that varies from one civilization to another defines the trends and limits of sociocultural evolution. Though culture itself forms under the influence of different factors (sociohistorical, natural, etc.) the significance of the general culture type for the sociopolitical organization is not at all reduced to the so-called ‘ideological factor’ (Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000c; Claessen 2000b). It influences crucially the essence of politicaf culture characteristic for a given society, ‘most probably revealing itself as fully as economic, religious, artistic potential from the very be­ginning’ (Zubov 1991: 59). In its turn, political culture determines human vision of the ideal sociopolitical model which correspond­ingly, may be different in various cultures. This way political cul­ture forms the background for the development of character, types and forms of complex political organization emergence, including the enrolling of this process along either the homoarchical or heterarchical evolutionary pathways. But real, ‘non-ideal’ social institutions are results of conscious activities (social creativity) of people to no small degree, though people are frequently not capable to realize completely global sociopolitical outcomes of their deeds aimed at realization of personal goals. People create in the social sphere (as well as in other spheres) in correspondence with the value systems they adopt within their cultures in the process of socialization. They apprehend these norms as the most natural, the only true ones.

Hence, it is evident that the general culture type is intrinsically connected with its respective modal personality type. In their turn, the fundamental characteristics of modal personality types are transmitted by means of socialization practices which correspond to the value system generally accepted in a given society and can influence significantly its political evolution (see Irons 1979: 9–10, 33–35; Ionov 1992: 112–129; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a: 309–312) though scholars usually tend to stress the opposite influence, i.e. the influence of political systems on socialization processes and personality types.

The ecological factor is also important for determination of the pathway which this or that society follows (Bondarenko 1998b; 2000). Not only natural environment but the sociohistorical one as well should be included into the notion of ‘ecology’ in this case. The environment also contributes a lot to the defining of a society’s evolutionary potential, creating limits to its advancement along the homoarchical or heterarchical axes. For example, there is no predestined inevitability of transition from the simple to complex society (Tainter 1990: 38; Lozny 2000) or from the early state to mature one (Claessen and van de Velde 1987: 20 etc.).

Let us discuss now the implications of the approach discussed above for the study of the state formation processes and ‘polito­genesis’ in general. The tendency to see historical rules always and everywhere the same results in gross perversion of historical real­ity. For example, concurrent political processes are declared con­secutive stages of the formation of the state. Besides, the features of already mature state are illegitimately attributed to its early forms and in consequence of this it becomes impossible to find any ‘normal’ early state practically anywhere.

The notion of ‘politogenesis’ was elaborated in the 1970s and 80s by Kubbel (e.g. 1988) who imployed it to define the process of state formation. But it has become evident by today that processes of archaic societies’ political evolution should not be reduced to the rise of the state exclusively because this is rather just one par­ticular version of those processes. We suggest to use this term in order to denote the formation of any types of complex political organization, which also looks more justifiable from the etymo­logical point of view: in ancient Greece the word politeia meant the political order of any type, and not ‘state’.

We believe that among the students of politogenesis one can observe a tendency to narrow the analysis to the study of the state formation process only. This entirely legitimate intention to re­strict and define the study field still leads to the underestimation of the fact that for long periods of time the state formation process was inseparably linked with other evolutionary processes (e.g. processes of religious evolution), and this seems to hinder any really profound explanation of the state formation processes them­selves. We believe that such explanations may be only achieved if the state formation processes are studied against background of all the other contemporary evolutionary processes.

It seems impossible to say that such an approach was always ignored (see e.g. Claessen and Skalnik 1978; Claessen 2000a [es­pecially p. 2]). However, notwithstanding substantive achieve­ments in the analysis of the general cultural context of state for­mation processes this problem still appears to be far from its real solution.

One of the causes of this situation can be defined as ‘polito-centrism’. Volens-nolens the state formation starts to be regarded as a central process of the evolution of medium complexity cul­tures not just because of initial definition of the research objective (which seems to be entirely legitimate); it starts to be regarded as an objectively central process, whereas this is not always true, be­cause in many cases other processes (e.g. sociostructural or relig­ious) could be more important (for details see Grinin 2001).

On the other hand, sure enough, there were not one but many models of politogenesis in the time of the transition from more simple societies to more complex (both socioculturally and tech­nologically) ones. The resultant cultures often differ from the state, but it is incorrect to consider them prestate structures, be­cause they could be well compared to the early state as regards their complexity, functions and causes of their formation.

Therefore, the evolutionary pathway within which the features of the state familiar to us are guessed retrospectively, is only one of the possible ‘branches’ of the politogenesis. But since later most alternative sociopolitical structures were destroyed by states, absorbed into states, or transformed into states7, it might be rea­sonable to recognize the ‘state’ branch of the politogenesis as ‘general’ and the alternative pathways as ‘lateral’.

This, however, does not deny the fact that the alternative socio­political structures mentioned above cannot be adequately de­scribed as prestate formations, that they are quite comparable with early states by range of their functions and level of their structural complexity. Therefore, it seems possible to designate them as state analogues. The term ‘state analogue’ underlines both typological and functional resemblance of such forms to the state and differ­ences in structure. The introduction of this term makes it possible to describe the process of politogenesis more adequately.

In order to find solutions for a certain range of political anthro­pology problems it is necessary to consider the genesis of early state in the general context of socioevolutionary processes coeval with it. This could make it possible to appreciate more exactly the correlation between general evolution and state formation proc­esses. For example, it seems evident that the early state formation is finally connected with general changes caused by the transition from the foraging to food production. This generally resulted in the growth of sociocultural complexity. This led to the appearance of the objective needs in new methods of organization of societies and new forms of contacts between them. But in different societies it was expressed in different ways. So, over long periods of time, the growth of sociostructural complexity, the exploitation of neighbors, development of commerce, property inequality and pri­vate ownership, growth of the role of religious cults and corpora­tions etc. could serve as alternatives to purely administrative and political decisions of above-mentioned problems. And in these terms, the early state is only one of forms of new organization of the society and intersociety relations.

As a result we could suggest the following points for the future study of the socioevolutionary processes in medium complexity cultures:

1) interrelatedness and inerconnectedness of the political as­pects of the politogenesis and the other aspects (religious, so­ciostructural etc.);

2) causes of underdevelopment and fragmentary character of the administrative institutions in the early states;

3) causes of relative easiness of the transition from one pattern of growing sociocultural complexity to another;

4) determining of sociopolitical evolution models by historical-cultural and geographical conditions.

NOTES

* This study was supported by grants from the Russian Foundation for the Humanities (RGNF # 01–03–00332a) and from the Russian Foundation for Basic Research (RFBR/RFFI # 01–06–80142).

1 Note, however, that in fact this was frequently essentially Spencerian vision which was implied in such cases; that is the evolution was perceived as ‘a change from an incoherent homogeneity to a coherent heterogeneity’ (Spencer 1972 [1862]: 71).

2 The state is understood throughout as ‘...a sufficiently stable political unit characterized by the organization of power and administration which is separated from the population, and claims a supreme right to govern certain territory and population, i.e. to demand from it certain actions irrespective of its agreement or disagreement to do this, and possessing resources and forces to achieve these claims’ (Grinin 1997: 20; see also Grinin 2000: 190).

3 See also its fundamental criticism by Mann (1986), the most radically negative attitude to this scheme expressed in categories of social evolu­tion ‘trajectories alternativity’ by Yoffee (1993), several collective works of recent years (Patterson and Gailey 1987; Ehrenreich et al. 1995; Kradin and Lynsha 1995; Kradin et at 2000; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a), proceedings of recent international conferences (Butovskaya et al. 1998; Bondareko and Sledzevski 2000).

4 There is considerable difference in the general ‘world-system’ and civi-lizational approaches. While the former tends to develop the globalistic viewpoint on history, the latter emphasizes regional trends and tendencies of evolution. At the same moment, our employment of the ‘world-system’ approach in this part of our paper, in our opinion must not be appre­hended as a contradiction within our overall ‘civilizational’ approach. First, there is an important aspect the respective approaches share: both of them stress supra-local (of more than one society) trends of changes in different spheres; and, second, pre-modern ‘world-systems’ as they are represented in the corresponding approach supporters’ works (except A. Gunder Frank’ s version [e.g. Frank and Gills 1993]) look very simi­larly with what is called ‘civilizations’ within another approach [e.g. Abu-Lughod 1989; Sanderson 1995; Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997]. Furthermore, it looks very much like that in the United States the general understanding of the necessity to study evolution and history on the supra-local level came through Wallerstein while in reality it was the civiuzational approach (especially of the Danilevsky – Spengler – Toynbee ‘brand’ ) for which this principle became most fundamental much earlier.

5 This appears to be especially relevant for those societies where extended families are dominated not by groups of brothers, but by individual ‘fathers’ (see e.g. Bromley 1981: 202–210).

6 Note that among not only humans but other primates too, the role of kin relations is greater in homoarchically organized associations (Thierry 1990; Butovskaya and Feinberg 1993: 25–90; Butovskaya 1993; 2000; Butovskaya, Korotayev, and Kazankov 2000).

7 However, such transformations could only happen when certain conditions were present. E.g. this could happen as a result of the influence of neighboring state systems.

REFERENCES

Abu-Lughod, J. L.

1989. Before European Hegemony: The World System AD 1250–1350. Oxford - New York: Oxford University Press.

Adams, R. N.

1975. Energy and Structure. Austin – London: University ofTexasPress.

Artemova, O. Yu.

1987. Lichnost’ i sotsial’ nye normy v rannepervobytnoy obshchine [Personality and Social Norms in the Archaic Community]. Moskva: Nauka.

1991. Egalitarnye i neegalitarnye pervobytnye obshchestva [Egalitar­ian and Inegalitarian Primitive Societies]. In Korotayev, A. V. and Chu-barov, V. V. (eds.), Arhaicheskoe obshchestvo: uzlovye problemy sotsi-ologii razvitiya [Archaic Society: Basic Problems of Evolutionary Sociol­ogy], (vol. 1, pp. 44–91). Moskva: IRI AN SSSR.

1993. Pervobytnyi egalitarizm i rannie formy sotsial’ noy differentsiatsii [Primitive Egalitarianism and Early Forms of Social Differentiation]. In Popov, V. A. (ed.) Rannie formy sotsial’ noj stratifikatsii: genezis, is-toricheskaja dinamika, potestarno-politicheskie funktsii [Early Forms of Social Stratification: Genesis, Historical Dynamics, Potestal-and-Political Functions] (pp. 40–70). Moskva: Nauka.

2000a. Initial Phases of Politogenesis. In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 54–72.

2000b. Monopolization of Information and Social Inequality. In Kra-din et al. 2000: 132–137.

Bakhta, V. M. and Senyuta, T. V.

1972. Lokal’ naja grappa, sem’ ja i uzy rodstva v obshchestve aborige-nov Avstralii [Band, Family, and Ties of Kinship in the Australian Abo­riginal Society]. In Reshetov, A. M. (ed.), Okhotniki, sobirateli, rybolovy [Hunters, Gatherers, Fishermen] (pp. 68–90). Leningrad: Nauka.

Barton, R. F.

1922. Ifugao Economics. Berkeley: University of California Press:

Beliaev, D. D.

2000. ‘Joint Government’ in Mesoamerican History. In Bondarenko and Sledzevski 2000: 13–14.

Berent M.

1994. Stateless Polis. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis manuscript. Cam­ bridge: Cambridge University.

1996. Hobbes and the ‘Greek Tongues’. History of Political Thought 17: 36–59.

2000a. Greece (11th–4th Centuries ВС). In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 228–254.

2000b. The Stateless Polis: Towards a New Anthropological Model of the Ancient Greek Community. In Kradin et al. 2000: 225–241.

Berezkin, Yu. E.

1995a. Alternative Models of Middle Range Society. ‘Individualistic’ Asia vs. ‘Collectivistic’ America? In Kradin and Lynsha 1995: 75–83.

1995b. Vozhdestva i akefal’ nye slozhnye obshchestva: dannye ark-heologii i etnograficheskie paralleli [Chiefdoms and Acephalic Complex Societies: Archaeological Data and Ethnographic Parallels]. In Popov, V. A. (ed.), Rannie formy politicheskoj organizatsii: ot pervobytnosti к gosudarstvennosti [Early Forms of Political Organization: From Primi-tivity to Statehood] (pp. 62–78). Moskva: Nauka.

2000. Once Again on Horizontal and Vertical Links in Structure of the Middle Range Societies. In Kradin et al. 2000: 220–224.

Bondarenko, D. M.

1994. Precolonial Benin: Personality, Authority and the Structure of Society. In Sabloff, J. A. and Lai, M. (eds.), State, City and Society (pp. 1–10). New Delhi: WAC-3.

1995a. Benin nakanune pervykh kontaktov s evropejtsami: Chelovek. Obshchestvo. Vlast’ [Benin on the Eve of the First Contacts with Europe­ans: Man, Society, Authority]. Moskva: IAf RAN.

1995b. Megacommunity as a Variant of Structure and Type of Soci­ety: Precolonial Benin. In Kradin and Lynsha 1995: 100–108.

1997. Teorija tsivilizatsij i dinamika istoricheskogo protsessa v dokolonial ‘noj Tropicheskoj Afrike [The Theory of Civilizations and the Dynamics of Historical Process in Pre-colonial Tropical Africa]. Moskva: IAf RAN.

1998a. ‘Homologous Series’ of Social Evolution. In Butovskaya, Ko­rotayev, and Khristoforova 1998: 98–99.

1998b. Mnogolinejnost’ sotsial’ noj evoljutsii i al’ ternativy gosudar-stvu. Vostokl: 195–202.

2000. ‘Homologous Series’ of Social Evolution and Alternatives to the State in World History (An Introduction). In Kradin etal 2000: 213–219.

2001. Doimperskij Benin: formirovanie i evoljutsija sistemy sot-sial’ no-politicheskikh institutov [Pre-Imperial Benin: Formation and Evolution of the System of Sociopolitical Institutions]. Moskva: IAfRAN.

Bondarenko, D. M. and Korotayev, A. V.

1999. Politogenez, “gomologicheskie rjady” i nelinejnye modeli sot­ sial’ noj evoljutsii (K kross-kul’ turnomu testirovaniju nekotorykh politan-tropologicheskikh gipotez) [Politogenesis, ‘Homologous Series’ and Nonlinear Models of Social Evolution (A Cross-Cultural Testing of Some Political Anthropological Hypotheses)]. Obshchestvennye nauki i sovre-mennost’ 5: 129–140.

2000a (eds.). Civilizational Models of Politogenesis. Moscow: IAf RAN.

2000b. Family Size and Community Organization: A Cross-Cultural Comparison. Cross-Cultural Research 34: 152–189.

2000c. Introduction. In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 5–31.

Bondarenko, D. M. and Sledzevski, I. V. (eds.)

2000. Hierarchy and Power in the History of Civilizations. Moscow: IAfRAN.

Bromley, Yu. V.

1981. Sovremennye problemy etnografii (ocherki teorii i istorii) [Modern Problems of Ethnography (Essays in Theory and History)]. Mo­skva: Nauka.

Bramfiel, E. M.

1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies: Comments. In Ehrenreih et al. 1995: 125–131.

Butovskaya M. L.

1993. Kinship and Different Dominance Styles in Three Species of the Genus Macaca. Folia Primatologica 60: 210–224.

1994. Universal’ nye printsipy organizatsii sotsial’ nykh sistem и pri-matov vkljuchaja cheloveka [Universal Principles of Social Systems’ Or­ganization of Primates Including the Humans]. Dr.Sc. thesis official summary. Moskva: IEA RAN.

2000. Biosocial Preconditions for Sociopolitical Alternativity. In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 35–53.

Butovskaya, M. L., and Feinberg, L. A.

1993. U istokov chelovecheskogo obshchestva. Povedencheskie aspekty evoljutsii cheloveka [At the Sources of Human Society. Ethologi-cal Aspects of Human Evolution]. Moskva: Nauka.

Butovskaya, M. L., Korotayev, A. V., and Kazankov, A. A.

2000. Variabilite des relations sociales chez les primates humains et non humains: a la recherche d’ un paradigme general. Primatologie 3: 319–363.

Butovskaya, M. L, Korotayev, A. V., and Khristoforova, О. В., (eds.) 1998. Sociobiology of Ritual and Group Identity: A Homology of Animal and Human Behavior. Concepts of Humans and Behavior Pat­terns in the Cultures of the East and the West: Interdisciplinary Ap­proach. Moscow: RSUH.

Carneiro, R. L.

1970. A Theory of the Origin of the State. Science 169: 733–738.

1981. The Chiefdom: Precursor of the State. In Jones, G. D. and Kautz, R. R. (eds.), The Transition to Statehood in the New World (pp. 37–79). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

1987. Cross-Currents in the Theory of State Formation. American Ethnologist 14: 756–770.

1991. The Nature of the Chiefdom as Revealed by Evidence from the Cauca Valley of Colombia. In Rambo, A. T. and Gillogly, K. (eds.), Pro­files in Cultural Evolution (pp. 167–190). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

2000. Process vs. Stages: A False Dichotomy in Tracing the Rise of the State. In Kradin et al. 2000: 52–58.

Chamblee, J. F.

2000. The Classic-Postclassic Transition in the Central Mixteca Alta, Oaxaca. Unpublished M.A. thesis manuscript. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona.

Chase-Dunn, Ch. and Grimes, P.

1995. World-System Analysis. Annual Review of Sociology 21: 387–417.

Chase-Dunn, Ch, and Hall, T. D.

1993. Comparing World-Systems: Concepts and Working Hypothe­ses. Social Forces 71: 851–886.

1994. The Historical Evolution of World-Systems. Sociological In­quiry 64: 257–280.

1995. The Historical Evolution of World-Systems. Protosoziologie 7: 23–34, 301–303.

1997. Rise and Demise. Comparing World-Systems. Boulder, CO –Oxford: Westview Press.

Chirkin, V. E.

1955. Ob izuchenii gosudarstvennykh obrazovanij, voznikavshikh v khode vosstanij rabov i krest’ jan [On the Study of States which Appeared in the Course of Slave and Peasant Rebellions]. Voprosy istorii 9: 57–64.

Chudinova, O. Yu.

1981. Muzhchiny i zhenshchiny v obshchestve aborigenov Avstralii [Men and Women in the Australian Aborigines’ Society]. In Malahov-skiy, K. V. (ed.), Puti razvitiya Avstralii i Okeanii. Istoriya, ekonomika, etnografiya (pp. 220–237). Moskva: Nauka.

Claessen, H. J. M.

2000a. Problems, Paradoxes, and Prospects of Evolutionism. In Kra­din et al. 2000: 1–11.

2000b. Structural Change. Evolution and Evolutionism in Cultural Anthropology. Leiden: Research School CNWS, Leiden University.

Claessen, H. J. M. and Skalnik, P. (eds.)

1978. The Early State. The Hague: Mouton.

Claessen, H. J. M. and van de Velde, P. (eds.) 1987. Early State Dynamics. Leiden: Brill.

Claessen, H. J. M, van de Velde, P, and Smith, M. E. (eds.) 1985. Development and Decline. The Evolution of Sociopolitical Or­ganization. South Hadley, MA: Bergin and Garvey.

Crumley, С. L.

1979. The Locational Models: An Epistemological Assessment for Anthropology and Archaeology. In Schiffer, M. (ed.), Advances in Ar­chaeological Method and Theory (vol. 3, pp. 141–173). New York: Aca­demic Press.

1987. A Dialectical Critique of Hierarchy. In Patterson, Т. С and Gailey, С W. (eds.), Power Relations and State Formation (pp. 155– 169). Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Association.

1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies. In Ehrenreih etal. 1995: 1–15.

2001. Communication, Holism, and the Evolution of Sociopolitical Complexity. In Haas J. (ed.), From Leaders to Rulers (pp. 19–33). New York etc.: Kluwer Academic/ Plenum Publishers.

Dozhdev, D. V.

2000. Rome (8th–2nd Centuries ВС). In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 255–286.

Dresch, P.

1984. The Position of Shaykhs among the Northern Tribes of Yemen. Man 19: 31–49.

Earle, T.

1978. Economic and Social Organization of a Complex Chiefdom: The Halelea District, Kiua ‘i, Hawaii. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

Ehrenreih, R. M., Crumley, С L., and Levy, J. E. (eds.) 1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies. Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Association.

Ferguson, Y.

1991. From Chiefdoms to City-States: The Greek Experience. In Earle, T. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy, and Ideology (pp. 169–192). Cambridge – New York: Cambridge University Press.

Frank, A. G. and Gills, В. К. (eds.)

1993. The World System: Five Hundred Years or Five Thousand? London – New York: Routledge.

Frantsouzoff, S. A.

1995. The Inscriptions from the Temples of Dhat Himyam at Raybun. Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 25: 15–27, tables I–II.

1997. Regulation of Conjugal Relations in Ancient Raybun. Pro­ceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 27: 47–62.

2000. The Society of Raybun. In Kradin et al. 2000: 258–265.

Fiihrer-Haimendorf, C.

1962. The Ара Tanis and Their Neighbours. London-New York: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

Gluckman, M.

1940. The Kingdom of the Zulu of South Africa. In Fortes, M. and Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (eds.), African Political Systems (pp. 25–55). Lon­don: Oxford University Press.

Goldman, I.

1970. Ancient Polynesian Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Grinin, L. E.

1997. Formatsii i tsivilizatsii. Gl. 4. Sotsial’ no-politicheskie, etniches-kie i dukhovnye aspekty sotsiologii istorii [Formations and Civilizations. Ch. 4. Sociopolitical, Ethnic, and Spiritual Aspects of the Sociology of History]. Filosofija i obshchestvo 5: 5–64.

2000. Proizvoditel’ nye sily i istoricheskij protsess [Productive Forces and Historical Process]. Moskva: Teis.

2001. Genesis gosudarstva как sostavnaja chast’ protsessa perehoda ot pervobytnosti к tsivilizatsii (obshchij kontekst sotsial’ noj evoljutsii pri obrazovanii rannego gosudarstva) [State Formation as a Component of the Civilization Formation Process (General Socioevolutionary Context of the Early State Formation)]. Filosofija i obshchestvo 4: 5–60.

Gurevich, A. Ya.

1972. Istorija i saga [History and the Saga]. Moskva: Nauka.

Ionov, I. N.

1992. Istoricheskij subjekt i al’ ternativy sotsial’ noj dejatePnosti. In Shemjakin, Ya.G. and Korotayev, A. V. (eds.), Al’ ternativnost’ istorii (pp. 109–131). Donetsk: DO SAMI.

Irons, W.

1979. Natural Selection, Adaptation, and Human Social Behavior. In Chagnon, N. A. and Irons, W. (eds.), Evolutionary Biology and Human Social Behavior. An Anthropological Perspective (pp. 4–39). North Sci-tuate, MA: Duxbury Press.

Kabo, V. R.

1986. Pervobytnaja dozemledel’ cheskaja obshchina [Primitive Preagricultural Community]. Moscow: Nauka.

Kobishchanov, Yu. M.

2000. The Community-Caste Systems. In Bondarenko and Sledzevski 2000: 63–64.

Korotayev, A. V.

1995a. Ancient Yemen. Some General Trends of Evolution of the Sabaic Language and the Sabaean Culture. Oxford – New York: Oxford University Press.

1995b. Mountains and Democracy: An Introduction. In Kradin and Lynsha: 60–74.

1995c. Nekotorye problemy sotsial’ noy evolyutsii arhaicheskih (i ne tol’ ko arhaicheskih) obshchestv [Some Problems of Social Evolution of Archaic (and not only Archaic) Societies]. Vostok 5: 211–220.

1995d. ‘Apologiya traybalizma’: Plemya как forma sotsial’ no-politicheskoy organizatsii slozhnyh nepervobytnyh obshchestv [‘Apolo­gia for Tribalism’: Tribe as a Form of Socio-Political Organization of Complex Non-Primitive Societies]. Sotsiologicheskij zhurnal 4: 68–86.

1996a. Pre-Islamic Yemen. Sociopolitical Organization of the Sabaean Cultural Area in the 2nd and 3r Centuries AD. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz Verlag.

1996b. Dva sotsial’ no-ekologicheskih krizisa i genezis plemennoy or­ganizatsii na Severo-Vostoke Yemena [Two Socio-Ecological Crises and Genesis of Tribal Organization in the Yemeni North-East]. Vostok 6: 18–28.

1996c. Ot vozhdestva к plemeni? Nekotorye tendentsii evolyutsii politicheskih sistem Severo-Vostochnogo Yemena za poslednie dve tysy-achi let [From Chiefdom to Tribe? Some Trends of Political Evolution of North-East Yemen in the Last Two Millennia]. Etnograficheskoe obozrenie 2: 81–91.

1997. Sabeyskie etyudy. Nekotorye obshchie tendentsii i faktory evolyutsii sabeyskoy tsivilizatsii [Sabaean Studies: Some General Trends and Factors of Evolution of the Sabaean Civilization]. Moskva: Vos-tochnaja literatura.

1998. Vozhdestva i plemena strany Hashid i BakJl [Chiefdoms and Tribes of the Land of Hashid and Bakll]. Moskva: IV RAN.

2000a. The Chiefdom: Precursor of the Tribe? (Some Trends of the Evolution of the Political Systems of the North-East Yemen in the 1st And 2nd Millennia A.D.) In Kradin et al. 2000: 242–257.

2000b. North-East Yemen (1st and 2nd millennia AD). In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 191–227.

Korotayev, A. V. and Bondarenko, D. M.

2000. Polygyny and Democracy: A Cross-Cultural Comparison. Cross-Cultural Research 34: 190–208.

Korotayev, A. V., Kradin, N. N., Lynsha, V. A., and de Munck, V. 2000. Alternatives of Social Evolution: An Introduction. In Kradin et al. 2000: 27–89.

Kowalewski, S. A.

2000. Cyclical Transformations in North American Prehistory. In Kradin et al. 2000: 177–187.

Kradin, N. N.

1992. Kochevye obshchestva (problemy formatsionnoj kharakteristiki) [Nomad Societies (Problems of Evolutionary Attribution)]. Vladivostok: Dal’nauka.

1996. Imperija hunnu [The Hsiung-nu Empire]. Vladivostok: Dal’nauka.

2000a. The Hsiung-Nu (200 ВС – AD 48). In Bondarenko and Koro­tayev 2000: 287–304.

2000b. Nomads, World-Empires, and Social Evolution. In Kradin et al. 2000: 274–288.

2000c. Politicheskaja antropologija [Political Anthropology]. Mo­skva: Ladomir.

Kradin, N. N., Korotayev, A. V., Bondarenko, D. M., de Munck, V., and Wason, P. K. (eds.)

2000. Alternatives, of Social Evolution. Vladivostok: FEB RAS.

Kradin, N. N. and Lynsha, V. A. (eds.)

1995. Alternative Pathways to Early State. Vladivostok: Dal’nauka.

Kubbel’, L. E.

1988. Ocherki potestarno-politicheskoj etnografii [Essays of Potestal and Political Ethnography]. Moskva: Nauka.

Levy, J. E.

1995. Heterarchy in Bronze Age Denmark: Settlement Pattern, Gen­der, and Ritual. In Ehrenreih et al. 1995: 41–53.

Lozny, L.

2000. Social Complexity: Necessity or Chance? In Bondarenko and Sledzevski 2000: 79–80.

Lynsha, V.

1998. From Chiefdom to Tribe: Svealand in AD. 400–1100. In Butov-skaya, Korotayev, and Khristoforova 1998: 99–100.

Mann, M.

1986. The Sources of Social Power. Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Meshkov, K. Yu.

1982. Filippiny [The Philippines]. In Cheboksarov, N. N. and Kuznet-sov, A. I. (eds.), Malye narody Indonezii, Malajzii i Filippin [Scanty Peo­ples of Indonesia, Malaysia and the Philippines] (pp. 175–226). Moskva: Nauka.

Nikitin, N. I.

1987. О formatsionnoj prirode rannikh kazachjikh soobshchestv (k postanovke voprosa) [On the Formational Nature of Early Cossack Communities (An Introduction)]. In Janin, V. L. (ed.), Feodalizm v Rossii [Feudalism in Russia] (pp. 236–245). Moskva: Nauka.

Olgeirsson, E.

1957. Iz proshlogo islandskogo naroda [The Past of the Icelandic People]. Moskva: Nauka.

Patterson, Th. С and Gailey, С W. (eds.)

1987. Power Relations and State Formation. Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Association.

Pavlenko, Yu.

1996. Istorija svitovoj tsivilizatsii. Sotsiokul’ turnij rozvitok ljudstva [History of World Civilization. Sociocultural Development of the Hu­mankind]. Kiiv: Lybed’.

2000. Proiskhozhdenie tsivilizatsii: al’ ternativnye puti [The Origins of Civilization: Alternative Pathways]. In Kradin et al. 2000: 115–128.

Quigley, D.

1999. The Interpretation of Caste. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Ritter, E. A.

1955. Shaka Zulu: The Rise of the Zulu Empire. London: Longmans, Green.

Rozner, I. G.

1970. Antifeodal’ nye gosudarstvennye obrazovanija v Rossii i na Ukraine v XVI–XVIII vv. [Antifeudal States in Russia and Ukraine in the 16th–18th Centuries]. Voprosy istorii 8: 42–56.

Sahlins, M. D.

1960. Evolution: Specific and General. In Sahlins, M. D. and Service, E. R. (eds.), Evolution and Culture (pp. 12-th). Ann Arbor, MI: Univer­sity of Michigan Press.

1972/1958. Social Stratification in Polynesia. Seattle – London: Uni­versity of Washington Press.

Sanderson, S. K., (ed.)

1995. Civilizations and World-Systems: Two Approaches to the Study of World-Historical Change. Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press.

Service, E. R.

1971/1962. Primitive Social Organization. An Evolutionary Perspec­tive. 2nd ed. New York: Random House.

Shtaerman, E. M.

1989. К probleme vuzniknovenija gosudarstva v Rime. Vestnik drev-nej istorii 2: 76–94.

Spencer, H.

1972/1862. On Social Evolution. Chicago: Aldine.

Steblin-Kamenskij, M. I.

1984. Mirsagi [The World of the Saga]. Leningrad: LGU.

Tainter, J. A.

1990. The Collapse of Complex Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge Universtiy Press.

Thierry, B.

1990. Feedback Loop between Kinship and Dominance: The Macaque Model. Journal of Theoretical Biology 145: 511–521.

Townsend, J. B.

1985. The Autonomous Village and the Development of Chiefdoms. In Claessen et al. 1985: 141–155.

Tuden, A. and Marshall, С

1972. Political Organization: Cross-Cultural Codes 4. Ethnology 11: 436–464.

Vavilov, N. I.

1921. Zakon gomologicheskikh rjadov v nasledstvennoj izmen-chivosti [The Law of Homologous Series in Hereditary Variability]. Sel ‘shoe i lesnoe khozjajstvo 1: 27–39.

1927. Geograficheskie zakonomernosti v raspredelenii genov kul’ –turnykh rastenij [Geographical Regularities in the Distribution of Cul­tured Plants]. Priroda 10: 41–56.

1967. Izbrannye proizvedenija [Selected Works]. Vol. 1–2. Lenin­grad: AN SSSR.

van der Vliet, E. Ch. L.

1987. Tyranny and Democracy. The Evolution of Politics in Ancient Greece. In Claessen, H. J. M. and van de Velde, P. (eds.), Early State Dynamics (pp. 70–90). Leiden: Brill.

Wallerstein, I.

1974. The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Ori­gins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press.

1979. The Capitalist World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer­sity Press.

1987. World-Systems Analysis. In Giddens, A. and Turner, J. H. (eds.), Social Theory Today (pp. 309–324). Cambridge: Cambridge Uni­versity Press.

Whyte, M. K.

1978. The Status of Women in Preindustrial Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Woodburn, J. С

1972. The Local Group among Hunters and Gatherers: An East Afri­can Example and its Implications. In Ucko, P. J., Tringham, R., and Dim-bleby, G. W. (eds.), Man, Settlement and Urbanism (pp. 193–206). Lon­don: Duckworth.

1979. Minimal Politics: The Political Organization of the Hadza of North Tanzania. In Shack, W. A. and Cohen, P. S., (eds.), Politics in Leadership: A Comparative Perspective (pp. 244–266). Oxford: Claren­don Press.

1980. Hunters and Gatherers Today and Reconstruction of the Past. In Gellner, E. (ed.), Soviet and Western Anthropology (pp. 95–117). Lon­don: Duckworth.

1982. Egalitarian Societies. Man 17: 431–451.

1988a. African Hunter-Gatherer Social Organization. Is it Best Under­stood as a Product of Encapsulation. In Ingold, Т., Riches, D., and Woodburn, J. (eds.), Hunters and Gatherers. I. History, Evolution and Social Change (pp. 31–64). Oxford: Berg Publishers.

1988b. Some Connections between Property, Power and Ideology. In Ingold, Т., Riches, D., and Woodburn, J. (eds.), Hunters and Gatherers. II. Property, Power and Ideology (pp. 10–31). Oxford: Berg Publishers.

Yoffee, N.

1993. Too Many Chiefs? (Or, Safe Texts for the ‘90s). In Yoffee, N. and Sherratt, A. (eds.), Archaeological Theory: Who Sets the Agenda? (pp. 60–78). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Zubov, A. B.

1991. ‘Vestminsterskaja model" i obshchestvennoe bytie Vostoka. In Zubov, А. В., Salmin, A. M., and Tajvan, L. L. (eds.), Retrospektivnaja i sravnitel’ naja politologija. Publikatsii i issledovanija, (vol. 1 pp. 50–75). Moskva: Nauka.